Добавил:
Опубликованный материал нарушает ваши авторские права? Сообщите нам.
Вуз: Предмет: Файл:
Ryder N., Griffiths M., Singh L. Commercial law - principles and policy 2012.pdf
Скачиваний:
17
Добавлен:
19.12.2022
Размер:
3.27 Mб
Скачать

Part 7 Chapter 1

The Government’s Policy towards Consumer Credit

Contents

 

Introduction

497

2â Evolution of the consumer credit market

498

3â Consumer debt, financial exclusion and over-indebtedness

501

Irresponsible lending

505

5â Regulation of irresponsible lending

506

Irresponsible borrowing

508

7â Ineffective legislative protection for consumers

510

8â A change of policy

514

9â Lessons from the United States

518

10â

Conclusion

519

11â

Recommended reading

520

 

 

 

1â Introduction

Since the introduction of the first credit card in 1966, the influential recommendations of the Crowther Committee on Consumer Credit (1971)1 and the introduction of the Consumer Credit Act 1974,2 creditors now allow debtors to access credit twenty-four hours a day and 365 days a year. The number of creditors and credit products has grown at an unprecedented rate. The evolution of the credit market was hastened by the deregulation of consumer credit legislation in the 1980s and 1990s. This chapter outlines how the relaxation of the consumer credit legislative frameworks resulted in an increase in the availability of ‘convenient credit’, which is defined as ‘credit that is granted by the creditor with little or no reference to the creditworthiness of the debtor’. This chapter identifies several problems that have arisen from access to ‘convenient credit’ (record levels of consumer debt, financial exclusion and over-indebtedness, an increase in irresponsible lending practices and ineffective legislative protection of consumers), which has resulted in a dramatic U-turn by the government towards

1 Known as the Crowther Committee.â 2â See below.

498

 

The government’s policy towards consumer credit

 

 

 

 

 

promoting access to ‘affordable credit’. Affordable credit comprises five basic

 

 

elements: (i) access to loans that are simple and transparent; (ii) lenders that are

 

 

sympathetic towards low income consumers’ circumstances; (iii) simple loan

 

 

application procedures; (iv) small loans over a short period of time; and (v)

 

 

affordable repayments.3 The chapter identifies several government initiatives

 

aimed at promoting access to affordable credit, including the creation of the

 

Social Exclusion Unit (SEU), the promotion of credit unions, the development

 

of Saving Gateway and the Financial Inclusion Fund.

2â Evolution of the consumer credit market

Access to consumer credit, which ‘less than a century ago barely existed’ has dramatically altered.4 Consumers are able to access credit over the World Wide Web, their interactive television sets, through telephone banking and retail outlets. This development is summarised by the National Association of Citizens Advice Bureau (NACAB):

In 1979 bank customers wanting to arrange a loan had to ensure that they were able to visit their branch office on a weekday between 9.30 a.m. and 3.30 p.m. Today the proliferation of telephone and Internet banking provides 24-hour access 365 days a year. An ever increasing number of companies have entered the personal finance market offering an ever more bewildering choice of products.5

The increased use of credit initially had a positive impact for consumers, a view initially held by the Crowther Committee, who concluded that ‘on balance consumer credit is beneficial, since it makes a useful contribution to the living standards and social wellbeing of the majority of the British people’.6 Similarly, Borrie commented on the benefits afforded by access to credit:

as inflation began to rise in the 1970s, it made no sense to wait before buying: the price would inevitably be higher if you did so. Two-digit inflation was a great boost to buying on credit, and buying a house on credit made the greatest sense of all because inflation ensured that the capital value of your house increased while your repayments took a gradually smaller percentage of your income. So the enormous expansion of credit in the 1960s and 1970s met a very real demand by the public which was expressed not in the ballot box but in the shops and in the bank manager’s parlour.7

3 National Consumer Council, Affordable Credit: a Model that Recognises Real Needs (National Consumer Council, London, 2005) 1.

4 M. Richards, P. Palmer and M. Bogdanova, ‘Irresponsible lending? A case study of a UK credit industry reform initiative’ (2008) 81(3) Journal of Business Ethics 499, 501.

5 National Association of Citizens Advice Bureau, Daylight Robbery: The CAB Case for Effective Regulation of Extortionate Credit (London, 2000).

6 Crowther Committee on Consumer Credit, as cited in C. Ironfield-Smith, K. Keasey, B. Summers, D. Duxbury and R. Hudson, ‘Consumer debt in the UK: attitudes and implications’ (2005) 13(2) Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance 132,134.

7 G. Borrie, ‘The credit society: its benefits and burdens’ (1986) Journal of Business Law (May) 181, 184.

499

2â Evolution of the consumer credit market

 

 

Furthermore, Scott and Black argued that:

from the customer’s viewpoint buying on credit has its advantages. It may simply be convenient either at the point of sale or in enabling payment to be made for something over a period. With major purchases consumers can obtain the present employment of products, services and property without the need for immediate payment; there is a good argument that the use of credit in this way is a desirable forms of forced saving for some people.8

The consumer credit market has undergone a revolution since the 1970s when the government’s legislative control over the sector was extremely restrictive.9 Indeed, prior to the publication of the Crowther Committee Report and the introduction of the Consumer Credit Act (CCA) 1974, the consumer credit legislative framework consisted of the restrictive and unsuitable Pawnbrokers Acts 1872–1960,10 the Moneylenders Acts 1900–1927 and the Hire-Purchase Act 1965.11 The Griffiths Commission stated that ‘there were strict quantitative limits imposed on the banks by the government. Building societies supplied mortgages for house purchases, but again these were rationed on the basis of rigid and conservative debt to income ratios’.12

The 1980s and 1990s saw the deregulation of the restrictive consumer credit legislation.13 Such measures included the abolition of controls on transactions in foreign exchange in 1979, the restrictions on banking lending being lifted, the removal of the reverse asset ratio in 1981 and the abolition of hire purchase controls in 1982.14 Keasey et al. noted that this deregulation ‘transformed borrowing into an acceptable, and necessary, part of many consumers’ lives … making buying on credit more attractive when compared with saving for consumer goods’.15 Other important measures included the move to allow banks to offer mortgages;16 the Building Societies Act 1986 liberalised the interest rate fixing agreements; the demutualisation of building societies occurred and

8C. Scott and J. Black, Cranston’s Consumers and the Law (Butterworths, London, 2000) 231. The Griffiths Commission stated that the ‘credit markets have grown to their present size because the services they have provided have responded to consumer demands. The result has been that consumers have been able to enjoy a higher standard of living than would have been the case if these markets had not existed’. The Griffiths Commission on Personal Debt: What Price Credit?

(Centre for Social Justice, London, 2005) 1.

9Richards et al., above n.4.

10For a more detailed discussion of this legislative framework J. Macleod, ‘Pawnbroking: a regulatory issue’ (2005) Journal of Business Law (March) 155.

11S. Brown, ‘The Consumer Credit Act 2006: real additional mortgagor protection?’ (2007)

Conveyancer and Property Lawyer (July/August) 316, 317.

12Griffiths Commission, above n. 8, at 21.

13E. Fernandez-Corugedo and J. Muellbauer, Consumer Credit Conditions in the United Kingdom,

Bank of England Working Paper No. 314 (London, 2006) 4.

14NACAB, above n. 5, at 6.

15See Ironfield-Smith et al., above n. 6, at 134.

16During this period mortgage borrowing increased by 300 per cent, largely due to the introduction of ‘right to buy’ legislation under the Housing Act 1980. See E. Kempson, Overindebtedness in Britain: A Report to the Department of Trade and Industry (Personal Finance Research Centre, Bristol, 2002).

500

 

The government’s policy towards consumer credit

 

 

 

 

 

the number of Internet mortgage providers increased in the latter part of the

 

 

1990s.17 All these legislative amendments resulted in an increase in the avail-

 

ability of credit.18 The then Department of Trade and Industry (DTI) shared this

 

view and stated that the consumer credit market had fundamentally changed

 

and that the variety of credit commodities available had grown at an unparal-

 

leled velocity.19 Similarly, HM Treasury stated that a majority of households had

 

witnessed a significant increase in ease of access to credit products.20

 

 

 

However, there is a ‘dark side’ to the consumer credit market, fuelled by

 

 

access to convenient credit and increased competition within the sector. This

 

 

‘dark side’ of the credit market is illustrated by record levels of consumer

 

 

debt,21 increasing evidence of irresponsible lending practices,22 the imposition

 

 

of extortionate interest rates,23 and ineffective legislative protection of con-

 

 

sumers.24 This was a point recognised by Ziegel, who in 1973 wrote that ‘even

 

 

under the most favourable circumstances a consumer credit orientated econ-

 

 

omy is bound to produce a number of casualties. These are the debtors who, for

 

 

one reason or another, have over-committed themselves and are unable to pay

 

 

their debts.’25 Despite an increase in the availability of convenient credit, there

 

are an increasing number of households who are forced to obtain credit from

 

sub-prime providers, who traditionally charge higher interest rates than banks

 

or building societies.26 Sub-prime providers of credit can be divided into three

 

categories: commercial cash loans,27 non-commercial cash loans28 and credit

 

 

tied to the purchase of goods.29 It has been estimated that 2.25 million people

 

are at risk in terms of access to affordable credit.30 Research conducted by the

 

17

Fernandez-Corugedo and Muellbauer, above n. 13, at 8–9.

 

18

E. Lomnicka, ‘The reform of consumer credit in the UK’ (2004) Journal of Business Law 129.

 

19

DTI White Paper, Fair, Clear and Competitive: the Consumer Credit Market in the 21st Century

 

 

 

(London, 2003).

 

20

HM Treasury, Promoting Financial Inclusion (London, 2004).

 

21

Credit Action, Debt Facts and Figures (Lincoln, 2011).

 

22

HM Treasury, above n. 20.

 

23

See E. Kempson and C. Whyley, Extortionate Credit in the UK, (DTI, London, 1999). Collard

 

 

 

and Kempson took the view that people on low income would borrow from lenders who would

 

 

 

charge annual percentage rates between 100 and 400 per cent. See S. Collard and E. Kempson,

 

 

 

Affordable credit: the Way Forward (Joseph Rowntree Foundation, Bristol, 2005) 1.

 

24

Lomnicka, above n. 18, at 129.

 

25

J. Ziegel, ‘Recent developments in Canadian consumer credit law’ (1973) 36(5) Modern Law

 

 

 

Review 479, 480.

 

26

FSA, In or Out? Financial Exclusion: a Literature and Research Review (London, 2000) 42.

 

27

This includes home credit companies, pawn brokers, sale and buy back, payday loans and

 

 

 

unlicensed money lenders. For a graphic illustration of the consequences of using home credit

 

 

 

companies see HM Treasury, Review of Christmas Savings Schemes (London, 2007).

 

28

This includes the government run Social Fund and Budgeting Loan Scheme, credit unions,

 

 

 

savings and loan schemes, community-based loan schemes, family and friends and informal

 

 

 

savings and loan schemes.

 

29

This includes agency mail order companies and rental purchase outlets.

 

30

P. Davis and C. Brockie, ‘A Mis-signalling problem? The troubled performance relationship

 

 

 

between credit unions and local government in the UK’ (2001) 27(1) Local Government

 

 

 

StudiesÂ1.